The principal behavioral postulate is. most preferred alternative from those

Similar documents
Chapter 4: Utility Function

CONSUMPTION BASICS. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Consumption Basics 1

EC422 Mathematical Economics 2

3/1/2016. Calculus: A Reminder. Calculus: A Reminder. Calculus: A Reminder. Calculus: A Reminder. Calculus: A Reminder. Calculus: A Reminder

Constrained Optimization

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2012 There are 8 questions. Answer as many as you can... Good luck!

1. Show that the rectangle of maximum area that has a given perimeter p is a square.

MTAEA Convexity and Quasiconvexity

Lecture 2 Optimization with equality constraints

Objectives Graph and Analyze Rational Functions Find the Domain, Asymptotes, Holes, and Intercepts of a Rational Function

Partial Derivatives. Partial Derivatives. Partial Derivatives. Partial Derivatives. Partial Derivatives. Partial Derivatives

Boolean Algebra. P1. The OR operation is closed for all x, y B x + y B

C:\jim\COURSES\8858\code-bk 2012\M2-2.gms Monday, January 09, :34:24 AM Page 1

EC5555 Economics Masters Refresher Course in Mathematics September Lecture 6 Optimization with equality constraints Francesco Feri

A CLASS OF INDIRECT UTILITY FUNCTIONS PREDICTING GIFFEN BEHAVIOUR. P.G. MOFFATT, School of Economics, University of East Anglia, UK.

1. Answer: x or x. Explanation Set up the two equations, then solve each equation. x. Check

Open and Closed Sets

Derivatives. Day 8 - Tangents and Linearizations

5.6 Exercises. Section 5.6 Optimization Find the exact maximum value of the function f(x) = x 2 3x.

Algebra Reviews & LP Graphic Solutions

Constrained and Unconstrained Optimization

c x y f() f (x) Determine the Determine the Approximate c : Replacin on the AP exam: under-approximation

Math 1120, Section 4 Calculus Test 2. November 5, 2008 Name. work. 1. (15 points) Consider the function f(x) = (2x + 3) 2 (x 1) 2.

Notes Lesson 3 4. Positive. Coordinate. lines in the plane can be written in standard form. Horizontal

( ) y #S, where! "[0,1]. In other words, if you connect any two

Tangent Planes and Linear Approximations

Competitive Prices as a Ranking System over Networks. Ehud Lehrer and Ady Pauzner Tel Aviv University July 2012

Let s go through some examples of applying the normal distribution in practice.

2. Write the point-slope form of the equation of the line passing through the point ( 2, 4) with a slope of 3. (1 point)

Differentiation. The Derivative and the Tangent Line Problem 10/9/2014. Copyright Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

Math 101 Exam 1 Review

MATH 19520/51 Class 6

The Fundamentals of Economic Dynamics and Policy Analyses: Learning through Numerical Examples. Part II. Dynamic General Equilibrium

) 2 + (y 2. x 1. y c x2 = y

Ricardain Model and Comparative Advantage! Chayun Tantivasadakarn! Faculty of Economics, Thammasat University!

MATHEMATICS II: COLLECTION OF EXERCISES AND PROBLEMS

Solution Methods Numerical Algorithms

Lectures on Challenging Mathematics. Integrated Mathematics 4 Analytic geometry and vector operations. Idea Math. Summer 2018.

Mathematical Themes in Economics, Machine Learning, and Bioinformatics

Lattice Polygon s and Pick s Theorem From Dana Paquin and Tom Davis 1 Warm-Up to Ponder

Pick s Theorem and Lattice Point Geometry

14.4: Tangent Planes and Linear Approximations

3.7 Rational Functions. Copyright Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

2.4. A LIBRARY OF PARENT FUNCTIONS

Graphs and transformations, Mixed Exercise 4

Unconstrained Optimization

UNIT 1 SIMILARITY, CONGRUENCE, AND PROOFS Lesson 10: Proving Theorems About Parallelograms Instruction

Multiplying and Dividing Rational Expressions

REF: Resource Elasticity Fairness with Sharing Incentives for Multiprocessors

Warm Up Simplify each expression. Assume all variables are nonzero.

What is linear programming (LP)? NATCOR Convex Optimization Linear Programming 1. Solving LP problems: The standard simplex method


Writing Equations of Parallel and Perpendicular Lines

Math 2 Spring Unit 5 Bundle Transformational Graphing and Inverse Variation

Quadratic Equations. Learning Objectives. Quadratic Function 2. where a, b, and c are real numbers and a 0

AM 221: Advanced Optimization Spring 2016

LP Graphic Solution & Solver for LP

Math 115 Second Midterm March 25, 2010

QUADRATIC FUNCTIONS TEST REVIEW NAME: SECTION 1: FACTORING Factor each expression completely. 1. 3x p 2 16p. 3. 6x 2 13x 5 4.

1.1 What is Microeconomics?

UNIT 8: SOLVING AND GRAPHING QUADRATICS. 8-1 Factoring to Solve Quadratic Equations. Solve each equation:

Curve Construction via Local Fitting

Math Analysis Chapter 1 Notes: Functions and Graphs

Lecture 6: Interpolation

Finding the Maximum or Minimum of a Quadratic Function. f(x) = x 2 + 4x + 2.

College Algebra. Fifth Edition. James Stewart Lothar Redlin Saleem Watson

MATHEMATICS LESSON PLAN

First of all, we need to know what it means for a parameterize curve to be differentiable. FACT:

Graphs of Parabolas. typical graph typical graph moved up 4 units. y = x 2 3. typical graph moved down 3 units

Linear Programming Problems: Geometric Solutions

3.3 Optimizing Functions of Several Variables 3.4 Lagrange Multipliers

The big picture and a math review

Unconstrained and Constrained Optimization

practice: quadratic functions [102 marks]

2. Suppose we drew many tangent lines for this second curve. How do the slopes of these tangent lines change as we look from left to right?

Working with Quadratic Functions in Standard and Vertex Forms

Math Analysis Chapter 1 Notes: Functions and Graphs

Chapter - 2: Geometry and Line Generations

Index. acronyms, list of, xvii asymmetric digital subscriber line (ADSL), tier structure, 4 asynchronous transfer mode (ATM), 2, 163

Simulation. Lecture O1 Optimization: Linear Programming. Saeed Bastani April 2016

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists Problem set 6: Linear programming

Chapter 02: Computer Organization. Lesson 02: Functional units and components in a computer organization- Part 1: Processor

Lesson 1: Analyzing Quadratic Functions

Analytical Solid Geometry

Shippensburg Math & Computer Day 2013 Individual Math Contest Solutions

Chapter 2: Rational. Functions. SHMth1: General Mathematics. Accountancy, Business and Management (ABM. Mr. Migo M. Mendoza

1.1 Graphing Quadratic Functions (p. 2) Definitions Standard form of quad. function Steps for graphing Minimums and maximums

The total cost function is linear. The fixed cost is $3482 and the total cost to produce 20 Trinkets is $4004. Find the total cost function.

Convexity and Optimization

Derivatives and Graphs of Functions

Curves, Tangent Planes, and Differentials ( ) Feb. 26, 2012 (Sun) Lecture 9. Partial Derivatives: Signs on Level Curves, Tangent

Applied Lagrange Duality for Constrained Optimization

x 2 + 8x - 12 = 0 Aim: To review for Quadratic Function Exam #1 Homework: Study Review Materials

9.1 Linear Inequalities in Two Variables Date: 2. Decide whether to use a solid line or dotted line:

Sec.4.1 Increasing and Decreasing Functions

9.1: GRAPHING QUADRATICS ALGEBRA 1

describes a ray whose endpoint is point A. g. A plane has no thickness. h. Symbols XY and YX describe the same line. i. Symbols AB

1 MATH 253 LECTURE NOTES for FRIDAY SEPT. 23,1988: edited March 26, 2013.

NATCOR Convex Optimization Linear Programming 1

Modeling Demand. Short Course on CGE Modeling, United Nations ESCAP. John Gilbert

Transcription:

Chapter 5 Choice

Economic Rationality The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The available choices constitute the choice set. How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

Rational Constrained Choice

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

Rational Constrained Choice Utility The most preferred of the affordable bundles. Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice Utility

Rational Constrained Choice

Rational Constrained Choice Affordable bundles

Rational Constrained Choice Affordable bundles

Rational Constrained Choice More preferred bundles Affordable bundles

Rational Constrained Choice More preferred bundles Affordable bundles

Rational Constrained Choice * *

Rational Constrained Choice ( *, *)isthemost preferred affordable bundle. * *

Rational Constrained Choice The most preferred affordable bundle is called the consumer ss ORDINARY DEMAND at the given prices and budget. Ordinary demands will be denoted by *(p 1,p 2,m) and *(p 1,p 2,m).

Rational Constrained Choice When * > 0 and * > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR. If buying ( *, *) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

Rational Constrained Choice ( *, *) is interior. ( *, *) exhausts the budget. * *

Rational Constrained Choice ( *, *) is interior. (a) ( *, *) exhausts the budget; p 1 *+p 2 *=m m. * *

Rational Constrained Choice * ( *, *) is interior. (b) The slope of the indiff. curve at ( *x*) *, *) equals the slope of the budget constraint. *

Rational Constrained Choice ( *, *) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted; p 1 *+p 2 *=m (b) the slope of the budget constraint, -p 1 /p 2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing ( *, *) are equal at ( *, *).

Computing Ordinary Demands How can this information be used to locate ( *, *) for given p 1, p 2 and m?

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences. 1 2 1 a b 2 Ux (, x ) x x

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences. Then 1 2 1 a b 2 Ux (, x ) x x MU U ax a x x b 1 1 1 2 1 MU 2 U x 2 1 a b 2 1 bx x

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is a b 2 1 1 1 2 2 dx U/ x ax x ax MRS dx U / x a b bx x bx 1 2 1 2 1 1.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is a b 2 1 1 1 2 2 dx U/ x ax x ax MRS dx U / x a b bx x bx 1 2 1 2 1 1. At ( *, *), MRS = -p 1 /p 2 so

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is a b 2 1 1 1 2 2 dx U/ x ax x ax MRS dx U / x a b bx x bx 1 2 1 2 1 1. At ( *, *), MRS = -p 1 /p 2 so * ax 2 p 1 * bp x 1 * 2 ap x *. (A) bx p 1 1 2 2

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. ( *, *) also exhausts the budget so * * 1 1 2 2 px px m. (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that bp x 2 1 ap x * * 2 1 * * 1 1 2 2 (A) px px m. (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that * bp x 1 2 ap x * 2 1 (A) Substitute * * p 1 p 2 m. (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we know that * bp x 1 2 ap x * 2 1 (A) Substitute * * p 1 p 2 m. (B) and get px p bp 1 * 1 1 2 x * 1 m. ap 2 This simplifies to.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. x * 1 am ( a b ) p 1.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. x * 1 am ( a b ) p 1. Substituting for * in then gives * * 1 1 2 2 px px m x * 2 bm ( a b) p 2.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So we have discovered that the most preferred affordable bundle for a consumer with Cobb-Douglas preferences a 1 2 1 b 2 Ux (, x ) x x is * * ( ) ( am bm x 1, x 2 ),. ( a b) p ( a b ) p 1 2

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. U ( x, x ) x x 1 2 1 a b 2 * bm ( a b ) p 2 x x * am 1 ( a b) p 1

Rational Constrained Choice When * > 0 and * > 0 and ( *, *) exhausts the budget, and indifference curves have no kinks, the ordinary demands are obtained by solving: (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = y (b) the slopes of the budget constraint, -p 1 /p 2, and of the indifference curve containing ( *, *) are equal at ( *, *).

Rational Constrained Choice But what if * = 0? Or if *=0? If either * = 0 or * = 0 then the ordinary demand ( *, *) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS =-1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS =-1 Slope = -p 1 /p 2 with p 1 >p 2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS =-1 Slope = -p 1 /p 2 with p 1 >p 2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case x y MRS =-1 * 2 p 2 Slope = -p 1 /p 2 with p 1 >p 2. * 0

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS =-1 Slope = -p 1 /p 2 with p 1 <p 2. * 0 x * 1 y p 1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case So when U(, )= +x 2, the most preferred affordable bundle is ( *, *) where * * y (x 1,x 2 ),0 if p 1 <p 2 p1 and * * y ( x1,x 2 ) 0, if p 1 >p 2. p2

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case MRS =-1 y p 2 Slope = -p 1 /p 2 with p 1 = p 2. y p 1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case y p 2 All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p 1 = p 2. y p 1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Which is the most preferred affordable bundle?

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case The most preferred affordable bundle

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case Notice that t the tangency solution is not the most preferred affordable bundle. The most preferred affordable bundle

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } = a

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } = a MRS = 0

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } MRS = - = a MRS = 0

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } MRS = - MRS is undefined = a MRS = 0

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } = a

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } Which is the most preferred affordable bundle? = a

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } The most preferred affordable bundle = a

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } * = a *

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } (a) p 1 *+p 2 *=m * = a *

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } (a) p 1 *+p 2 *=m (b) * = a * * = a *

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = m; (b) * = a *.

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = m; (b) * = a *. Substitution from (b) for * in (a) gives p 1 *+p 2 a *=m

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = m; (b) * = a *. Substitution from (b) for * in (a) gives p 1 *+p 2 a *=m which gives * m p ap 1 2

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = m; (b) * = a *. Substitution from (b) for * in (a) gives p 1 *+p 2 a *=m which gives m x * * am 1 ; x 2 p1 ap2 p1 ap2.

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case (a) p 1 * + p 2 * = m; (b) * = a *. Substitution from (b) for * in (a) gives p 1 *+p 2 a *=m which gives m x * * am 1 ; x 2 p1 ap2 p1 ap2 A bundle of 1 commodity 1 unit and a commodity 2 units costs p 1 + ap 2 ; m/(p 1 + ap 2 ) such bundles are affordable..

Examples of Kinky Solutions - - the Perfect Complements Case U(, ) = min{a, } * am p ap 1 2 x m ap = a * 1 1 p1 2